The Impacts of Environmental Regulation on the U.S. Economy

Concern regarding the economic impacts of environmental regulations has been part of the public dialogue since the beginning of the U.S. EPA. Even as large improvements in environmental quality occurred, government and academia began to examine the potential consequences of regulation for economic growth and productivity. In general, early studies found measurable but not severe effects on the overall national economy. Although price increases due to regulatory requirements outweighed the stimulative effect of investments in pollution abatement, they nearly offset one another. However, these studies also highlighted potentially substantial effects on local labor markets due to the regional and industry concentration of plant closures.

More recently, a substantial body of work examined industry-specific effects of environmental regulation on the productivity of pollution-intensive firms most likely to face pollution control costs, as well as on plant location and employment decisions within firms. Most econometric-based studies found relatively small or no effect on sector-specific productivity and employment, though firms were less likely to open plants in locations subject to more stringent regulation compared to other U.S. locations. In contrast, studies that used economy-wide models to explicitly account for sectoral linkages and intertemporal effects found substantial sector-specific effects due to environmental regulation, including in sectors that were not directly regulated.

It is also possible to think about the overall impacts of environmental regulation on the economy through the lens of benefit-cost analysis. While this type of approach does not speak to how the costs of regulation are distributed across sectors, it has the advantage of explicitly weighing the benefits of environmental improvements against their costs. If benefits are greater than costs, then overall social welfare is improved. When conducting such exercises, it is important to anticipate the ways in which improvements in environmental quality may either directly improve the productivity of economic factors—such as through the increased productivity of outdoor workers—or change the composition of the economy as firms and households change their behavior. If individuals are healthier, for example, they may choose to reallocate their time between work and leisure. Although introducing a role for pollution in production and household behavior can be challenging, studies that have partially accounted for this interconnection have found substantial impacts of improvements in environmental quality on the overall economy.

Keywords

Subjects

In the 1960s increased awareness and concern about the negative consequences of environmental pollution on human health and ecosystems spurred a national approach to environmental policy and regulation in the United States (Griswald, 2012). The U.S. Council on Environmental Quality (U.S. CEQ) was formed in 1970 to advise the president on the environment, and the first Earth Day took place in April of that same year, with over 20 million Americans participating. Both the National Environmental Policy Act and the Clean Air Act were also signed into law in 1970 , significantly expanding the federal government’s role in controlling air pollution. The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (U.S. EPA) was established on December 2, 1970 , to implement the requirements of these two major pieces of legislation (Lewis, 1985). The Clean Water Act followed in 1972 . 1

Although environmental regulations reduce emissions of harmful pollutants, thus generating health and other benefits for the American public, they also raise a plant’s production costs because they require installation and operation of pollution controls or changes in production processes that would otherwise not be undertaken. Almost immediately, the ability to balance environmental protection and the costs of pollution control requirements was tested. In 1971 , the U.S. EPA Administrator, William D. Ruckelshaus, rejected the timetable submitted for bringing Union Carbide’s Marietta, Ohio, plant into compliance with Clean Air Act requirements. Union Carbide responded by threatening to lay off a large number of workers. The U.S. EPA negotiated with the company on its emissions reduction schedule while preserving workers' jobs. This was done without compromising the environmental goal of reducing sulfur dioxide emissions at the plant, which declined 70% by April 1972 (Lewis, 1985).

From the beginning it also has been recognized that the potential negative effects on overall economic growth, productivity, and employment, as well as on specific industries should be considered alongside the positive consequences of improving environmental quality. In part, this balanced approach was likely motivated by the significant slowdown in U.S. productivity growth, uptick in inflation, and, by the mid-1970s, doubling of the unemployment rate that coincided with the expansion of federal oversight into areas such as environmental quality. 2 To better understand the potential effects of environmental regulation on the economy several government reports were commissioned to investigate the potential impacts on a wide array of measures, including national economic growth, industries and firms, employment, and consumers (e.g., U.S. CEQ, 1971). As data became available to study the impact of regulations retrospectively, the academic community also weighed in with studies of its own.

In the United States, current practice in federal government economic analyses of environmental regulation is to explicitly weigh the gains to society from environmental protection against the costs, measured in terms of changes in net social welfare. At the same time, economic analyses continue to examine how those welfare changes are distributed throughout the economy. Although a particular environmental regulation may result in an overall net gain to society, this may not be true for particular subsets of the economy. Understanding who is positively and negatively impacted by a particular policy is important when contemplating policy options.

This article is organized as follows. Section 1 summarizes research on the part of the federal government into the economic impacts of U.S. environmental regulation. Building on this early work, Section 2 discusses the academic literature on the impacts of environmental regulation on overall productivity and growth, and Section 3 reviews the literature on impacts on particular sectors of the economy, with specific emphasis on industry productivity, labor markets, and plant entry and exit decisions. Section 4 discusses expanding the notion of overall economic impacts to think about welfare effects of environmental regulation. Section 5 describes efforts to explicitly consider benefits when modeling the economy-wide welfare effects of environmental regulation. Section 6 concludes by discussing several areas ripe for additional research.

Early Government Studies on the Economic Impacts of Environmental Regulation

The results of the macroeconomic study indicated that the national economy would be significantly, though not “severely” impacted by pollution abatement costs to implement the Clean Air Act. Pollution abatement costs were assumed to affect the economy through higher product prices and new demand for pollution abatement equipment and services. In the absence of adjustments in macroeconomic monetary or fiscal policy, price increases outweighed the stimulative effect of investments in pollution abatement, reducing the growth rate of U.S. Gross National Product (GNP) by 0.3 percentage points and increasing the unemployment rate by 0.1 to 0.2 percentage points over the 1972 to 1976 period. However, the study also showed that employment declines were nearly offset by increased employment created by pollution control investments. When monetary and fiscal policy adjustments were incorporated, they offset the slowdown in GNP and increase in unemployment but at the cost of more rapid inflation and a further decline in the balance of international trade (U.S. CEQ et al., 1972). 3

The microeconomic studies summarized in the report were based on analyses of the economic impacts of environmental regulations on 11 specific industries (e.g., auto manufacturing, pulp and paper, petroleum refining). Consistent with the macroeconomic study, the authors characterized the results as indicating that none of the industries studied would be “severely impacted” (i.e., the long-term viability of these industries was not seriously threatened). The report estimated that for some industries prices would increase (by an annual average of between zero and 2% over the 1972 to 1976 period, depending on the industry), indicating some pass-through of costs. However, it also concluded that “profits will decline for some firms in most of the industries because firms will not be able to pass on the full cost of pollution abatement to consumers in the form of higher prices” (U.S. CEQ et al., 1972).

The early interaction between the newly created U.S. EPA and Union Carbide also highlighted a concern that environmental regulations could result in the layoff of workers at particular plants or even plant closures. However, as with other economic impacts, there was no empirical literature available that could provide a basis for estimates of national employment impacts associated with newly promulgated environmental regulations. The 1972 report summarized results from the microeconomic studies related to plant closures and employment effects. Of the approximately 12,000 plants in the industries studied, approximately 200–300 plants would be likely to close between 1972 and 1976 due to environmental regulations. However, the report noted that many of these plants were likely to have closed anyway because they were economically vulnerable for other reasons (U.S. CEQ et al., 1972). The employment impact from the projected plant closures was estimated to be approximately 50,000 to 125,000 jobs lost between 1972 and 1976 or about 1% to 4% of total employment in those industries. This would amount to an increase in national unemployment of approximately 0.05% (U.S. CEQ et al., 1972). The report warned, however, that the impact could be substantially higher if the economy was not at full employment. It is important to note that these estimates were not a net impact, since they did not include the number of people who found work in these industries over the same time period.

While the microeconomic studies in the 1972 report focused only on regulated industries, the macroeconomic study aimed to include all sectors of the economy, including pollution abatement activities. Macroeconomic impact modeling conducted as part of subsequent government reports found that growth in pollution abatement activities had a stimulative impact on the U.S. economy—creating additional jobs and decreasing the unemployment rate—relative to what would have occurred absent regulation (U.S. CEQ, 1979; DRI, 1981). Another U.S. CEQ report suggested that more efficient plants may have expanded production to make up for plants that closed (U.S. CEQ, 1978).

Initial concern about widespread job loss in the economy was, to a large degree, alleviated by empirical evidence. On the basis of self-reports from affected industries, the U.S. EPA found 118 plant closures between 1971 and 1977 , affecting over 21,900 employees, were reportedly due to environmental regulations. 4 This estimate is about half the size of the minimum estimate projected in the 1972 report (U.S. CEQ, 1978; Haveman & Smith, 1978). The Department of Commerce also surveyed plant closings due to pollution control requirements and found 131 of them between 1974 and 1977 , noting that 75% of permanent closings were not solely due to environmental regulation. As the economy improved over this time period, the number of plant closings reported each year also declined (Rutledge, Drieling, & Dunlap, 1978). Another Department of Commerce survey indicated that in over 60% of plant closures, plant age or facility obsolescence was a contributing factor (Segal & Dunlap, 1977). The 1978 U.S. CEQ report observed that closures were more likely to occur at plants that were older, smaller, less-efficient, and marginally profitable, absent pollution control requirements (U.S. CEQ, 1978).

Although effects of environmental regulation on the overall U.S. labor market were not as substantial as anticipated, these reports acknowledged that individual plant “closures and the unemployment that they cause may be significant for the communities that they affect” (U.S. CEQ, 1978). In particular, substantial industry- and location-specific effects might occur due to the geographic concentration of plant closures in “older industrial towns already suffering from relatively high unemployment rates” (U.S. CEQ, 1978). Data collected by the U.S. EPA demonstrate that layoffs between 1971 and 1982 that were due, at least partially, to environmental regulation were concentrated in the primary metals, chemical, pulp and paper, and food processing industries. About 40% of the layoffs occurred in the upper Midwest, and another 28% occurred in the Northeast (U.S. EPA, 1982).

Academic Literature on the Impact of Environmental Regulation on Overall Productivity and Growth

A key concern that motivated research into the impacts of environmental regulation on the economy was the significant slowdown in productivity growth that occurred at the same time as expansion of federal oversight into the environmental arena (Gray, 2015). 5 Initial interest by academic economists built on government-sponsored studies conducted in the early 1970s (e.g., U.S. CEQ et al., 1972). Using data on the costs of air and water pollution abatement and Solow growth accounting, Denison (1978, 1979)—a founder of growth accounting and an economist at the Brookings Institution at the time—was one of the first to empirically assess the impact of environmental regulations on productivity growth (i.e., the rate at which output per unit of input increases over time). 6 Denison estimated that, compared with the long-run growth rate of output per unit of input from 1948 to 1973 of just under 2%, environmental regulations resulted in an annual decline of between-0.10 and -0.20 percentage points between 1969 and 1978 .

Christainsen and Haveman (1981a, 1981b) questioned several aspects of the data, methodology, and interpretation in Denison’s growth accounting studies. They constructed indices for “regulatory intensity,” based on the cumulative number of major pieces of public regulatory legislation, including, but not limited to the environment (Christainsen & Haveman, 1981a). They used these indices to econometrically estimate the contribution of federal regulatory requirements to the slowdown in the growth of labor productivity. They concluded that regulations were responsible for between 12% and 21% of the 1.3 percentage point slowdown in productivity for manufacturing during 1973–1977 , relative to the 1958–1965 period. Separately, on the basis of their own work and a survey of other studies, Christainsen and Haveman (1981b) estimated that between 8 & 12% of the productivity slowdown could be attributed specifically to the cost of meeting environmental regulations.

About a decade later, Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1990) used a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model to examine the impact of environmental regulations on the long-run growth of the U.S. economy. CGE models simulate the workings of a market economy and can be used to capture how the imposition of a regulation ripples through the entire economy, affecting both individual sectors and economy-wide aggregates. Jorgenson and Wilcoxen’s dynamic CGE model divided the U.S. economy into 35 sectors, with behavioral parameters estimated from a time-series data set. Comparing steady states with and without environmental regulation, they estimated that regulation had reduced the level of real GNP by 2.6%. During the period 1973–1985 , they estimated that the growth rate of GNP had been reduced by 0.2%. By sector, they found that pollution controls had the largest effects on chemicals, coal mining, motor vehicles, petroleum refining, primary metals, and pulp and paper. Using the same model, Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1993) estimated that the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 would reduce the level of GNP by an additional 0.6%.

Academic Literature on the Economic Impacts of Environmental Regulation on Specific Sectors

While the overall effects of environmental regulation on productivity and economic growth continue to be metrics of interest, effects on different subsets of the economy are also highly relevant when gauging the impacts of regulation. For instance, one might wish to understand how prices and quantities of goods in affected sectors respond to regulation, or whether the costs of meeting the requirements of a regulation result in plant closures, additional barriers of entry for new firms, or particularly large impacts on small businesses. Likewise, it might be important to understand how a regulation affects energy production and prices, employment in particular sectors, and the ability of consumers to switch to available substitutes or absorb increased prices for certain products.

Federal agencies promulgating new regulations are required by statute or executive order to estimate some of these impacts. For instance, Executive Order 13563 states: “Our regulatory system must protect public health, welfare, safety, and our environment while promoting economic growth, innovation, competitiveness, and job creation. It must be based on the best available science.” Executive Order 13211 requires, to the extent permitted by law, that agencies prepare a statement of energy effects when a regulatory action is expected to significantly affect energy supply, distribution, or use. The Regulatory Flexibility Act directs agencies to pay particularly close attention to the economic impacts of regulation on small businesses.

Although there is a wide range of economic impacts of potential interest to policymakers and the public when evaluating the effects of an environmental regulation, this entry focuses on only a subset of these. Specifically, this article summarizes the empirical literature on productivity impacts in pollution-intensive industries, the potential effect of environmental regulation on plant location and the U.S. labor market.

Productivity Studies

With little to suggest environmental regulations were a large drag on overall productivity growth, researchers began to investigate whether pollution-intensive industries newly subject to regulation experienced more significant productivity impacts. One early study by Gollop and Roberts (1983) estimated the effect of sulfur dioxide emissions regulations on productivity growth in the electric power industry from 1973 to 1979 . 7 They estimated that the overall impact of the regulations on constrained utilities, which incurred both increased fuel and capital costs, to be an average decline in annual productivity growth of almost 0.6 percentage points per year. As the period of analysis also corresponded with a sharp rise in fuel costs, a key empirical challenge was to separate fuel switching induced by the regulation—from high- to low-sulfur coal—from the general rise in fuel prices.

Gray (1987) represented another important early study of the effect of environmental regulation on the productivity growth of pollution-intensive industries. He econometrically estimated the impact of federal environmental and occupational safety and health regulations on total factor productivity (TFP) growth for a wide array of manufacturing industries for the years 1958 to 1978 . 8 (Total factor productivity is the amount of output produced as a function of all plant inputs, including labor, capital, materials, and energy.) He found that 30% of the slowdown in TFP growth could be attributed to the imposition of government regulations. However, only about one-third of the 30% was specifically attributable to environmental regulations.

Similarly, Barbera and McConnell (1990) estimated the impact of environmental regulations on TFP for five of the most polluting industries. For the paper industry, they found that pollution abatement accounted for 30% of the decline in TFP in 1970–1980 compared with 1960–1970 . For the chemical, iron and steel, and stone, clay, and glass industries estimates ranged from a 10% to a 12% decline, while TFP actually increased for nonferrous metals over this time period. Unlike previous work, the authors were able to differentiate between direct effects (i.e., the need to increase total inputs for the same level of output when increasing abatement) and indirect effects (i.e., potential changes in the production function, which may be positive or negative).

Economists have continued to use detailed industry- and plant-specific data to investigate the effects of environmental regulations on pollution-intensive industries, while improving on the empirical techniques of early studies. In general, they continued to find a relatively small or no effect of environmental regulation on firm- or plant-level productivity. For instance, Repetto, Rothman, Faeth, and Austin (1997) asserted that there is a bias in traditional measures of productivity because a reduction in bad outputs (pollution) is not accounted for in those measures. When Domazlicky and Weber (2004) accounted for polluting outputs, they found that while there were costs associated with environmental regulations for the six chemical sectors investigated, they were not correlated with a reduction in productivity.

Berman and Bui (2001b) also pointed out a number of potential problems with earlier studies. First, heterogeneity bias may exist, as dirtier plants may also be less productive, making abatement appear to reduce productivity. (The opposite effect may occur for cleaner plants.) Second, abatement expenditures may be difficult to classify and may overstate the true economic costs of environmental regulation. To avoid these problems, the authors construct a TFP measure for U.S. refineries in the Los Angeles air basin using physical quantities. Although abatement costs were high due to strict air quality regulations, they found that refinery productivity actually rose during the 1987 to 1992 time period in the Los Angeles air basin, in contrast to declining productivity for refineries in other parts of the country that were not subject to the regulations.

Several studies are notable because of their use of sophisticated empirical techniques and detailed U.S. plant-level data from the U.S. Census of Manufactures and the Pollution Abatement and Cost Expenditure (PACE) survey. 9 Gray and Shadbegian (2003) examined how the impact of pollution abatement costs on productivity varies by type of pulp and paper mill over the 1979–1990 period. They found significant impacts on productivity for integrated mills, though not for non-integrated mills. They found no significant differences between older and newer plants. For the same time period, Shadbegian and Gray (2005) considered effects on paper mills, refineries, and steel mills and found that abatement expenditures generally had no significant effect on the productivity of non-abatement inputs. As in their previous paper, they examined subgroups of plants, those with dirtier production technologies and with more end-of-line abatement, but they did not find significant differences. Becker (2011) and Greenstone, List, and Syverson (2012) relied on differences in environmental stringency across counties in and out of attainment with the National Ambient Air Quality Standards to identify the impact of environmental regulation on the productivity of manufacturing plants. Becker (2011) found no statistically significant effect on productivity for plants in counties with higher environmental costs. Greenstone et al. (2012) estimated that for plants in heavily polluting industries, the nonattainment designation was associated with a 2.4% decline in TFP in plants that emitted the targeted pollutants. Estimated separately, ozone and carbon monoxide-emitting plants in nonattainment counties had productivity losses of about 2%. Sulfur dioxide emitters saw no significant change in TFP. TFP-emitting plants experienced a productivity increase of about 1.0%.

Plant Entry and Exit Decisions

Another key question that has arisen in the literature is whether compliance costs due to environmental regulations affect plant location decisions. Some U.S. counties—geographic and governmental jurisdictions within each state—face more stringent regulations when they are out of attainment with the National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS) for criteria air pollutants (e.g., particulate matter, ozone). In addition, because states frequently are responsible for implementing and enforcing federal regulations, it is possible that differences in monitoring and enforcement may cause the costs of compliance to vary across states.

Bartik (1985) is an important early paper in the plant location literature because it sets out the analytic framework for how differences in costs across locations influence siting decisions. Levinson (1996) extended this framework to explicitly consider the role of environmental regulatory costs. If compliance costs differ across locations or by type of plant, this can influence firm-level decisions about where to locate new plants and how to shift production among existing plants. Relying mainly on cross-sectional data, early empirical studies did not find evidence that environmental regulations affected U.S. plant location decisions (e.g., Carlton, 1983; McConnell & Schwab, 1990; Levinson, 1996). However, later studies that had access to panel data and more refined empirical techniques to better account for spatial correlation across locations, omitted variable bias, and plant- and location-specific effects found that higher compliance costs had a significant negative effect on plant location, particularly in the most pollution-intensive industries (Shadbegian & Wolverton, 2010). 10

Among the panel studies, it is relatively common to use attainment status with one or more NAAQS regulations as a proxy for environmental regulatory stringency. Henderson (1996) found evidence that manufacturing plants that were relatively high emitters of volatile organic compounds and nitrogen oxides were less likely to locate in counties out of attainment with the ozone NAAQS and that a county that came into attainment with the ozone NAAQS (and therefore was no longer subject to additional regulatory scrutiny) attracted about 8% more plants than a county that did not change status. Kahn (1997) found that manufacturing plants were less likely to close in counties out of attainment for particulate matter. However, provided they remained open, these plants grew more slowly over the 1982 to 1988 period.

Examining four polluting manufacturing industries, Becker and Henderson (2000) estimated that counties out of attainment with the ozone NAAQS attracted 26%–45% fewer plants than counties in attainment between 1967 and 1992 . In addition, they found that the further out of attainment a county was, the larger the estimated loss in new plants. In a similar study, Millimet and List (2004) examined how ozone attainment status affected plant entry and exit in pollution-intensive industries in New York from 1980 to 1990 . They found that factors such as a higher proportion employed in manufacturing, smaller populations, and higher wages help mitigate the effects of nonattainment on plant entry and exit. Condliffe and Morgan (2009) found that nonattainment of the ozone NAAQS had, on average, a statistically negative effect on plant entry in U.S. counties between 1996 and 1998 , but that this effect was mainly concentrated in the more pollution-intensive manufacturing industries.

List, McHone, and Millimet (2003) is one of the few studies to examine the impact of attainment status on the relocation of existing plants. Using data from New York, they found that a county that changed ozone attainment status between 1980 and 1990 experienced more than a 50% change in the flow of newly relocating plants. In particular, counties out of attainment and therefore subject to more stringent environmental standards attracted significantly fewer relocating plants than counties in attainment.

Labor Market Impacts

The potential employment impacts of environmental policy have been of concern since the Clean Air Act first was implemented, and interest continues. Analytically, the impacts of environmental regulation on employment are quite difficult to disentangle from other economic changes and conditions that affect employment. Because environmental regulation shifts economic activity toward less-polluting activities, employment impacts are a mix of potential declines and gains over time, across regions, and across industries of the economy. In addition to impacts on the directly regulated sectors, environmental regulations often increase demand for pollution control equipment and services needed for compliance. Moreover, a regulation that increases the costs of a primary input such as electricity may cause a decrease in the demand for labor in energy-intensive industries.

Microeconomic theory of production and factor demand describes how firms adjust their demand for inputs, such as labor, in response to changes in economic conditions. Researchers have used this framework to represent pollution abatement requirements as changes in quasi-fixed factors of production (Berman & Bui, 2001a), an increase in the price of pollution (Greenstone, 2002), an increase in pollution abatement costs (Morgenstern, Pizer, & Shih, 2002), an emissions tax (Holland, 2012), an increase in the price of capital (Deschênes, 2014), or an increase in energy prices (Deschênes, 2012). Impacts on firm-level labor demand can be decomposed into substitution and output effects. The substitution effect measures a change in employment as the firm responds to a change in input price, holding output constant. For example, with only capital and labor inputs, if the price of capital increases, the firm will substitute toward increased use of labor to produce the same level of output. With three or more productive factors, the substitution effect depends on the cross-elasticities of labor demand. The change in input price may also change the firm’s marginal cost of production, which then may affect the firm’s profit-maximizing level of output. The output effect measures how employment changes as the firm adjusts output to maximize profits, while holding relative input shares constant. As the output and substitution effects may be positive, negative, or some combination of the two, theory alone cannot predict the sign of the total impact of regulation on labor demand at regulated firms.

Overall, the economics literature finds little evidence that environmental regulations have had a significant impact on employment in regulated sectors and generally does not speak to the sign or magnitude of the overall effect of regulation on national employment. 11 Berman and Bui (2001a) examined the impact of local air quality regulations on employment in manufacturing plants relative to similar plants that did not face the same regulations. They found that even though regulations impose large costs on plants, they had a statistically insignificant effect on employment. Ferris, Shadbegian, and Wolverton (2014) also used a quasi-experimental empirical approach and found that relative to similar but unregulated plants, employment impacts from Phase I of the sulfur dioxide cap-and-trade program were close to zero for regulated utilities. Gray, Shadbegian, Wang, and Meral (2014) found that pulp mills subject to certain air and water regulations experienced relatively small and not always statistically significant decreases in employment. Curtis (2018) found a small negative impact of the nitrogen oxides cap-and-trade program on manufacturing employment, with impacts primarily occurring through decreased hiring rates, rather than increased separation rates. Sheriff, Ferris, and Shadbegian (2016) found negative impacts of ozone regulations on employment at electric utilities, with no accompanying changes in electricity generation, possibly indicating labor-saving technical change.

Other research on employment effects in regulated sectors, such as Greenstone (2002) and Walker (2011, 2013), suggests that counties subject to stricter air quality regulation may generate fewer manufacturing jobs than less regulated ones. However, because they identified employment impacts by comparing nonattainment with similar attainment areas, employment impacts are likely overstated; they are “double counted” to the extent that regulation caused plants to locate in one area of the country rather than another (Greenstone, 2002). List, Millimet, Fredriksson, and McHone (2003) found some evidence that this type of geographic relocation may be occurring. Kahn and Mansur (2013) examined manufacturing employment impacts of air regulations by pairing a regulated county with a neighboring, less regulated county, while controlling for differences in electricity price and labor regulation. They found limited evidence that air regulations caused employment to be lower on net within a county border pair. Although regulation may cause labor to relocate across a border, since one county’s loss is another’s gain, such shifts cannot be transformed into an estimate of a national impact on employment.

If employment impacts are anticipated in related but not directly regulated sectors, then a general equilibrium approach would likely better capture those impacts. However, existing CGE models used to analyze the overall impacts of environmental regulation almost always assume full employment. One way to incorporate involuntary unemployment into CGE models as an equilibrium condition has been to use a reduced form approach consistent with the notion that frictions in the marketplace prevent wages from adjusting to their market-clearing level. Modelers often specify a wage curve, based on the empirical observation of Blanchflower and Oswald (1994) that real wages are a decreasing function of the unemployment rate. This approach amounts to an exogenous assumption regarding the amount of unemployment within the labor market.

Dissou and Sun (2013) specified a wage curve to examine the welfare and employment implications of different ways of recycling revenues from a carbon cap-and-trade system. They found relatively small effects on employment for low- and high-skilled workers across scenarios, noting that this is unsurprising, given that carbon-intensive industries tend to use relatively more capital than labor (i.e., as such, one would expect them to shed more capital than labor in response to the policy). Likewise, Rivers (2013) incorporated a wage curve into a highly stylized three-sector static CGE model to examine the employment implications of renewable energy policies. Rivers found that subsidies increase equilibrium unemployment. Böhringer, Rivers, Rutherford, and Wigle (2012) used a CGE model to assess the labor market impacts of a feed-in-tariff policy in the electricity market in Ontario. They found that while increasing employment in “green” manufacturing, the policy had the opposite effect on employment in the rest of the economy and increased the unemployment rate overall. The authors acknowledged that external effects and technical change are ignored in the static model, and in certain cases their inclusion might produce a different outcome. Böhringer, Keller, and van der Werf (2013) used a CGE model of Germany to investigate the impacts of renewable energy promotion. They found that the possibilities for enhancing welfare and employment are quite limited, hinging crucially on the subsidy rate and financing mechanism.

CGE models that explicitly model wage-setting mechanisms often adopt labor market models from the labor economics literature. There are a number of wage-setting mechanisms, including efficiency wages, collective wage-bargaining, job search and matching models, and the explicit incorporation of other types of wage rigidities. The efficiency wage model is predicated on the idea that employers can increase worker productivity by paying above-market wages. In the collective wage-bargaining model, above-market wages result from negotiations between firms and labor unions with some degree of market power. Job search and matching models assume that finding a job requires time and effort and is inherently stochastic. The higher the ratio of unemployed to vacancies, the lower the probability of finding a job. 12

Balistreri (2002) laid out a methodology for incorporating two salient features of the job search and matching model into a CGE framework: “(1) supplying labor for production is costly in terms of the foregone reservation wage and an individual’s chance of not being matched to a job (i.e., becoming unemployed); and (2) there is an externality by which the risk of an individual not being matched is affected by the aggregate behavior of other agents.” He then demonstrated how this formulation of the job search and matching model operates within a dynamic CGE model of the United States when simulating a cap-and-trade policy to reduce carbon emissions. 13 Babiker and Eckaus (2007) introduced wage rigidities by limiting sectoral labor mobility and sectoral wage adjustment in a multiregion global CGE model. Dixon, Johnson, and Rimmer (2011) allowed for potential disequilibrium in the U.S. labor market by specifying three states: employed, unemployed, and not in the labor force, where employed labor is differentiated by industry, occupation, and region. The model also assumed a cost associated with changing employment states (Dixon & Rimmer, 2002).

Expanding the Notion of Overall Economic Impacts to Think about Social Welfare

Although changes in gross domestic or gross national product (GDP or GNP) and productivity have often been reported by government and academics as a metric for understanding the overall impact of an environmental regulation on the U.S. economy, they also have long recognized its shortcomings as a way to capture the full effects of policy on social well-being or welfare.

Executive orders signed under Presidents Nixon and Ford directed federal agencies to evaluate the potential effects of new regulation on the economy through the conduct of “Quality of Life Reviews” and “Inflation Impact Statements” (Morgenstern, 1997; OMB, 1997). The stated objective of a Quality of Life Review was to minimize the burden of environmental regulations on businesses. Inflation Impact Statements were broader; their purpose was to monitor agency activity for potentially inflationary actions and to conduct an inflation impact analysis (OMB, 1997). Economists hired to oversee these analyses concluded, however, that a regulation could not be inflationary unless its costs to society exceeded its benefits. As a result, they began conducting benefit–cost analyses (BCAs) of new major regulations as a way to meet executive order requirements. 14

A BCA that quantifies the social benefits and costs associated with a regulation seeks to answer the question, whether it is theoretically possible for the “gainers” from the policy to fully compensate the “losers” and still remain better off (U.S. EPA, 2010). 15 In this context, the measure used to gauge a regulation’s effect on the economy is the net change in social welfare that households experience. The net change in welfare is derived “by summing all of the benefits that accrue as a result of a policy change (including spillover effects) less costs imposed by the policy on society (including externalities)” (U.S. EPA, 2010). Since spillovers and externalities are nonmarket transactions, quantifying private costs and benefits is not a sufficient proxy for estimating the costs and benefits of a new regulation to society. Social cost represents the total burden that a regulation will impose on the economy. It is defined as the sum of all opportunity costs incurred as a result of a regulation, where an opportunity cost is the value lost to society of all goods and services that will not be produced and consumed in the presence of regulation as resources are reallocated away from consumption and production activities toward pollution abatement (U.S. EPA, 2010). Social benefits are also measured in terms of opportunity cost (OMB, 1997). 16

Why Move Beyond Impacts on Productivity and GDP to Consider Effects on Economic Welfare?

GNP or GDP has been recognized as “a flawed measure of economic welfare” because a number of factors that affect one’s quality of life are not included, such as leisure, health status, crime, and the environmental quality (Jones & Klenow, 2016). 17 In addition, these measures may be misleading due to double counting. For example, a regulation that requires firms to invest in new capital in a given year will result in a large increase in the investment component of GDP. However, capital also affects the availability of goods and services that can be consumed over a much longer time period, which is also captured in the consumption component of GDP (Paltsev & Capros, 2013). To avoid double counting, studies sometimes report changes in household consumption as an indicator of social welfare. However, as with GDP, this measure excludes consideration of how a new policy affects leisure and other quality of life factors such as environmental quality. 18 Another previously discussed alternative, economic productivity, is narrowly focused on the degree to which a policy affects the amount of output that can be produced using a given amount of inputs.

Economists use the concepts of equivalent variation (EV) and compensating variation (CV) to explore how a policy affects social well-being. Both of these are monetary measures of the change in utility brought about by changes in prices and incomes. The difference between them depends on whether one assumes the policy change has already occurred (EV) or is not yet in place (CV). For instance, EV measures what a consumer would be willing to pay to avoid an increase in prices (and thus, a decline in real income) resulting from a regulation going into effect. In contrast, CV measures how much a consumer would need to be compensated to accept changes in prices and income such that the consumer achieves the same level of utility experienced prior to the policy shock. In addition, changes in welfare encompass more than just market activities—for instance, there is a monetary value to leisure.

Literature on the Social Cost of U.S. Environmental Regulation

Hazilla and Kopp (1990) is an early example of a study that examined the welfare impact of environmental regulations on the economy. Relying on a 36-sector dynamic CGE model, they estimated the social cost of the U.S. Clean Air and Clean Water Acts for 1981 to 1990 expressed in terms of compensating variation. 19 They found that all sectors of the economy were affected, with the greatest impacts of the regulation falling on electric utilities, motor vehicles, crude oil and natural gas, primary metals, and chemicals. Sectors that were not directly regulated but supplied key intermediate goods also experienced significant negative impacts on output and labor productivity. Their estimate of the social cost of the regulations (about $980 billion) was more than 50% greater than the U.S. EPA’s equivalent engineering cost estimate. Hazilla and Kopp (1990) noted the importance of this result, since “very few policymakers have recognized that social costs can exceed private expenditures.” They state that the difference between the two measures is “a direct result of household behavior in which leisure is substituted for consumption.”

Two studies by the U.S. EPA on the benefits and costs of the Clean Air Act demonstrate how impacts on the economy differ when expressed in terms of economic welfare relative to GNP. The U.S. EPA (1997) relied on the CGE model used in Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1990) to retrospectively examine the sectoral impacts and aggregate effects of the Clean Air Act from 1970 to 1990 . As measured by changes in prices and output, the sectors most impacted were motor vehicles, petroleum refining, and electricity generation. The aggregate effect on GNP was estimated as a reduction in the long-run rate of GNP growth of 0.2%, with the 1990 level of GNP 1% lower than in the no-control scenario. The impact on social welfare, measured in terms of equivalent variation, was considerably smaller than the change in GNP, even though benefits of the Clean Air Act were not included in the CGE model.

The U.S. EPA (2011) study of the prospective effects of the Clean Air Act Amendments from 1990 to 2020 used a dynamic, forward-looking 35-sector CGE model. It found substantial secondary effects of compliance costs on the overall economy, a large portion of which likely result from energy price increases and the diversion of capital from activities that enhance long-term productivity to investment in pollution control equipment in the industrial sector. Once again, it found that GDP is not a particularly good measure of the welfare impact of a policy. In a cost-only scenario (i.e., no benefits included), GDP in 2020 was $108 billion lower than in the no-control case, while social welfare, measured as equivalent variation, was 25% smaller than the effect on GDP (about $82 billion lower than in the no-control case) due to the reallocation of some of the household’s time to leisure instead of labor. Unlike the U.S. EPA’s retrospective analysis, an additional scenario included some of the health benefits of the Clean Air Act. We discuss these in the next section.

Incorporating Benefits into Economy-Wide Modeling of Welfare Effects from Environmental Regulation

Due to the many ways in which economic activity is linked to environmental quality it is not possible to provide a full accounting of the effect of environmental policy on economic productivity and social well-being without also taking into account the beneficial effects and their impact on the economy. As policies change the environment, they may either directly improve the productivity of economic factors (e.g., reduced depreciation from acidic deposition, increased productivity of outdoor workers) or change the composition of the economy as firms and households change their behavior (e.g., labor–leisure choices).

There has been growing awareness that these interconnections between the environment and the economy are important for understanding the net effect of a policy on the economy and overall social well-being (Carbone & Smith, 2013). However, introducing a role for the environment into production and household behavior at an economy-wide scale is an area of applied analysis that is still developing. The suite of studies that have partially incorporated pollution into these types of frameworks have found substantial impacts on the overall economy of improvements in environmental quality. This section discusses the ways in which improvements in environmental quality can have a significant effect on economic activity and literature that explicitly accounts for the relationship between pollution and productivity when estimating the social welfare of air regulations.

Relationship between Pollution and Productivity

Although much of the initial literature focused on the connection between economic activity and compliance with environmental regulations, recent work has shown that understanding the way benefits from improving environmental quality interact with economic activity is also important for understanding the overall impacts of regulation. In fact, many estimates of the benefits associated with environmental policies leverage changes in market activity that complement household consumption of nonmarket goods and services as environmental quality varies. For example, households’ willingness to pay for environmental improvements is commonly estimated on the way spatial and/or temporal variation in environmental quality affects housing prices due to its influence on housing demand (Palmquist, 2005). Similarly, studies leveraging observed housing market behavior in response to variation in environmental amenities have estimated households’ willingness to pay for improvements in health (Gayer, Hamilton, & Viscusi, 2002). Benefits from improvements in environmental quality are also routinely estimated from consumers’ willingness to trade off other consumption for improved environmental quality in their recreation decisions (Phaneuf & Smith, 2005).

Human health has an important and direct connection with both economic activity and environmental quality. Degredation of environmental quality, such as air pollution, can increase the incidence of premature mortality (Levy, Baxter, & Schwartz, 2009; Fann et al., 2012; Tagaris et al., 2009). While vulnerable populations such as children and the elderly are particularly susceptible to the effects of pollution, environmental degradation also impacts the mortality rate of working-age individuals, thereby having a direct effect on labor force participation (U.S. EPA, 2011). Similarly, the morbidity effects of pollution can impact labor supply due to the effect on sick days taken (i.e., the extensive margin), as well as worker productivity while on the job (i.e., the intensive margin) (e.g., Vennemo, 1997). 20 Restrictions on an individual’s time endowment also affect the proportion allocated to work versus leisure activities. Pollution-related morbidity effects also increase demand for medical goods and services, which means those resources are not available for other productive uses in the economy (Matus, Yang, Paltsev, Reilly, & Nam, 2008). Although the size of these resource shifts may be relatively small, consideration of their effect on economic activity may still be warranted, particularly given the highly distorted state of healthcare markets.

In addition, environmental degradation affects the health of children in ways that are potentially different than for adults. First, children can be more vulnerable to pollution due to normal childhood activities and behavior patterns. According to U.S. EPA (2013a), “Children generally eat more food, drink more water, and breathe more air relative to their size than adults do, and consequently may be exposed to relatively higher amounts of environmental contaminants.” Second, children may be more vulnerable to pollution because they are still developing physically and may, therefore, be more easily harmed. The effects of environmental quality on children’s health impacts economic activity through multiple channels. In a dynamic setting, changes in the health risks faced by children, in the form of mortality and development, can have long-term implications for the economy through impacts on future labor supply and worker productivity. Furthermore, pollution-related illnesses in children can affect labor supply when parents and guardians have to take time off from work to provide care (Salkever, 1982).

Changes in environmental quality also impact the availability and productivity of other inputs to production. For example, atmospheric and deposition effects of air pollution can lead to materials damages, thereby increasing the depreciation rate of physical capital (U.S. EPA, 1999; Saha & Eckelman, 2014) and causing damages to buildings and structures of cultural and historical significance (Grosclaude & Soguel, 1994), which may impact regional tourism (Kling, Revier, & Sable, 2004). Similarly, air pollution has the potential to affect agriculture and forestry through its direct effect on vegetation via induced foliar injury, reduced annual growth rates, and induced root loss (U.S. EPA, 2007). Visible foliar injury can reduce the desirability of leafy crops, (e.g., spinach, lettuce) and ornamentals (e.g., petunias, geraniums, poinsettias). Discoloration and early shedding of leaves from air pollution can also have notable welfare effects in areas where foliage is highly valued (e.g., scenic vistas, fall foliage).

Literature Incorporating Benefits into Economy-Wide Analysis of Environmental Regulation

It has been estimated that environmental regulations prevent substantial numbers of premature deaths ever year and have a significant effect on rates of morbidity (U.S. EPA, 2011). A number of researchers have modeled the way these improvements in human health may interact with the economy using CGE models. Several of the initial studies were conducted in Europe. Vennemo (1997) was one of the first to incorporate environmental externalities into an applied CGE model of the Norwegian economy. Morbidity associated with air pollution was assumed to impact labor supply at both the extensive and intensive margins and was modeled as pollutant-specific labor shocks. While the early work of Vennemo was limited in its ability to capture some of the complex connections between the economy and the environment, it provided insights into their potential importance. Environmental feedbacks significantly reduced consumption of goods and services as well as overall social welfare.

A decade later, Mayeres and van Regemorter (2008) studied the effect of health impacts from air pollution on the European economy. Their study pushed the science forward by incorporating some aspects of mortality, morbidity, and non-health impacts of air pollution from the energy sector as non-separable elements of households’ utility functions in a general equilibrium framework. In other words, the study allowed for the behavior of households to be affected by changes in health status and environmental quality. Morbidity was modeled as both reducing households’ time endowment directly and as a labor productivity shock. By modeling a portion of the labor morbidity effect as a shock to labor productivity, Mayeres and van Regemorter attempted to capture the role of paid sick leave, whereby some households will remain financially whole in the face of changes in morbidity, while firms see a change in the productivity of their labor force. The study also incorporated the medical costs of pollution-induced mortality and morbidity more fully into the model by considering the effect of air pollution on private and public spending for medical services and household’s time endowments within a bidirectional coupling of the economy and the environment.

Researchers in the United States also began to incorporate health impacts from air pollution into a prominent multiregion, global CGE model (i.e., the Emission Prediction and Policy Analysis [EPPA] model). To date, the health effects version of the model has been used to study the impact of historical ozone and particulate matter air pollution in the United States (Matus et al., 2008), Europe (Nam, Selin, Reilly, & Paltsev, 2010), and China (Matus et al., 2012), and future ozone pollution globally (Selin et al., 2009). To incorporate premature mortality, the model accounted for the damages to households in terms of total factor consumption, including leisure, while also accounting for the cumulative economic effect of reduced labor, consumption, and investment associated with premature mortality. To incorporate pollution-induced morbidity, the model accounted for the reduced time available for labor and/or leisure, the increased demand for medical services, and cumulative economic effects from those changes.

Two studies have estimated how including the benefits of air pollution regulation affects social welfare. Matus et al. (2008) estimated that by 2000 air pollution regulations in the United States provided a welfare improvement (measured in terms of equivalent variation) of nearly $400 billion [ 1997 $], with households being willing to pay another $250 billon [ 1997 $] to avoid the remaining damages from air pollution. 21 They also estimated that consumption of final goods was 5.4% higher in 2000 due to improvements in air quality than in a world without those environmental policies. The U.S. EPA conducted a similar study looking at the expected economy-wide impacts of all regulations promulgated thus far under the Clean Air Act Amendments (U.S. EPA, 2011). The study modeled two scenarios in a CGE framework: a “cost-only” scenario that introduced the compliance costs of the regulations into the model, and a “labor force-adjusted” scenario that modeled both the costs and some human health benefits, specifically the mortality risk and morbidity reductions expected to accrue to the labor force as an increase in their available time endowment. The scenario also included expected reductions in the demand for medical services as a result of reduced morbidity.

Figure 1. Economy-Wide Impacts of the Clean Air Act Amendments.

Source: U.S. EPA (2011).

The U.S. EPA’s analysis highlights a number of important insights. First, it showed how important accounting for the beneficial impacts of environmental policies are when trying to assess their economic impacts. When accounting for the human health impacts of the policy, the expected effect on GDP was less than half of what it was when only compliance costs were considered. Inclusion of health benefits in the control case also reduced negative impacts on sectors such as electricity, mining, and minerals and increased the positive impacts on sectors such as computer equipment manufacturing. Second, as previously discussed, it demonstrated that GDP is not a particularly good measure of the welfare impact of a policy. Recall that, even when only considering the costs of the policy, the change in GDP was significantly different than the change in welfare. Figure 1 shows that this issue is exacerbated once the human health impacts of the policy are included. In the initial years the impact of the policy on GDP was negative, while the policy was immediately welfare-improving (with this effect growing over time). This is primarily driven by changes in the time endowment, which allows households to engage in more leisure while also supplying more labor, increasing both consumption and welfare.

As already mentioned, other nonmarket impacts of environmental policies may also be important for determining effects on social welfare. For example, Finnoff and Tschirhart (2008) coupled ecological and economic general equilibrium models of the Alaskan economy with a food web model of Alaska’s marine ecosystem to study the economic impacts of regulating commercial fishing. They found potentially notable general equilibrium effects due to the direct effects in the regulated sector and indirect effects on the tourism sector. In addition, while most of the primary factors (capital and labor) utilized in the directly regulated industry resided outside of Alaska, they found that the domestic labor market was affected due to reductions in real income as well as changes in the tourism sector. 22

Carbone and Smith (2013) tested the quantitative importance of general equilibrium welfare effects when there are changes in human health, nonmarket ecosystem services, and non-use existence services that result from improving environmental quality. Specifically, they added sector-specific sulfur and nitrogen oxide emissions factors that have effects on lakes and forests through acidic deposition, along with negative human health impacts, to a CGE model. They also included two nonmarket services associated with recreational fisheries and tree cover and a nonuse existence value associated with general habitat services. The authors conducted a series of experiments to compare the welfare change with and without the general equilibrium effects from changes in air quality improvements. For a policy resulting in a 40% emissions reduction, roughly the magnitude of reductions from the Clean Air Act Amendments, and focusing only on improvements to recreational fisheries, they found that including general equilibrium effects increases the estimate of the welfare improvement by 12% to 55%. 23 These results led the authors to conclude that even when the value of nonmarket services is a small fraction of the aggregate value of the economy, the general equilibrium effects stemming from how changes in environmental quality affect household behavior may be notable.

BOX 1. CASE STUDY: REMOVING LEAD FROM GASOLINE

Lead had been used by refiners as an additive in gasoline to increase octane levels and improve engine performance since the 1920s. This practice led to high levels of lead in the atmosphere and soil. Studies in the early 1980s increasingly tied lead exposure to negative health effects in children (e.g., learning problems, hyperactivity, and lower IQ) and adults (e.g., increased blood pressure and hypertension). In addition, automobile manufacturers were required to install catalytic converters in new cars beginning with the 1975 model year to reduce emissions of hydrocarbons, nitrogen oxides, and carbon monoxide. However, catalytic converters lose their effectiveness when exposed to lead.

To protect public health, particularly children in urban areas, and to address complications for catalytic converters, the U.S. EPA required retailers to begin selling some amount of unleaded gasoline in 1974. As awareness of the health impacts of lead exposure grew, so did demand for more rapid removal of lead from gasoline. In 1982 the U.S. EPA promulgated a tradable performance standard that established a system of property rights for lead use, which could be traded between refiners in order to lower costs. The standard was made tradable in part due to concerns that small refiners might find it difficult to meet the new standards and would benefit from additional flexibility (Hahn & Hester, 1989). In 1985 the U.S. EPA further tightened the standards. In addition to trading, the U.S. EPA allowed refiners to bank emissions reductions across quarters in that first year of the more stringent program. Lead in gasoline was banned completely in 1996.

Ex post assessments found that trading and banking were used extensively. Larger refiners tended to reduce lead in their fuel, generating extra permits, and then sold these rights to smaller refiners with relatively higher refining costs. Banking provisions were mainly utilized by large refiners, though smaller refiners also benefited from this flexibility, since it increased the pool of permits available for purchase (Hahn & Hester, 1989). While researchers did not rely on the econometric and general equilibrium modeling approaches discussed in other sections of this article, the limited data available indicate substantial cost savings (Newell & Rogers, 2006). Hahn and Hester (1989) stated that “It is reasonable to estimate that the cost savings to refiners from lead rights trading and banking amounted to hundreds of millions of dollars.” Kerr and Newell (2003) also found evidence that periods when the trading and banking provisions were used corresponded with more rapid adoption of octane-enhancing technologies to replace the use of lead.

Systematic ex ante benefit–cost estimates are not available for the early lead phase-down program, but the U.S. EPA conducted an extensive benefit–cost analysis for the 1985 regulation (U.S. EPA, 1985). For 1986 to 1988, benefits of a tenfold reduction in lead content were estimated to outweigh costs by about 12 to 1 (e.g., in 1986, benefits of $7.8 billion compared with costs of $600 million in 1983 dollars). When blood pressure-related benefits to adults, which were estimated with less certainty, were excluded from the analysis, benefits still exceeded costs by 2 to 1 (Nichols, 1997). The finding of sizable net benefits associated with phasing out lead in gasoline is remarkable, given the knowledge gaps at the time. The U.S. EPA was only able to quantify avoided costs of medical care and remedial education for children with blood levels above a certain threshold. The willingness to pay for avoided lasting health and cognitive impacts were not included in the analysis but would likely have been of a larger magnitude than the included benefits (Keohane & Olmstead, 2007). In a recent study, Wolfe et al. (2016) found that economy-wide feedbacks of cognitive damages from leaded aviation fuel, still in use in the United States, are also significant. In particular, they found economy-wide welfare losses using a dynamic CGE model were 54% larger than static partial equilibrium estimates.

Significant Outstanding Research Questions

There are a number of important questions regarding the impacts of environmental regulation on the U.S. economy that remain unresolved. We briefly discuss several, emphasizing their saliency to ongoing public debate and the need for renewed attention in the research arena.

Unifying Structural Framework for Understanding Economic Impacts of Environmental Regulation

Analyses of major regulation traditionally focus on estimating the overall costs and benefits of a policy to society. The distribution of those costs and benefits is also of great interest, but such analyses face a number of methodological and empirical challenges. Identifying the particular sectors or subsectors affected, how costs are passed through to households and firms, and the ways in which households and firms respond can be quite difficult to analyze, and sometimes results in unexpected effects (Kolstad, 1999, 2014). Decisions regarding whether to expand or reduce production at existing facilities or whether to open new facilities have implications for when and how many workers are hired. Likewise, labor input decisions may manifest as changes in how many workers are hired or laid off, the types of workers hired or laid off, the wages and benefits offered, or the number of hours worked. These decisions, in turn, are linked to the productivity of firms, sectors, and ultimately the overall economy.

On the Basis of the existing literature and the relative magnitude of environmental regulations compared with the size of the U.S. economy, one would anticipate that for most environmental regulations, economic impacts likely have limited or no macroeconomic implications (Arrow et al., 1996; Ferris et al., 2014). 24 However, lack of an overarching structural framework that coherently links individual decisions to their macroeconomic implications also hinders the ability to analyze potential economy-wide impacts of environmental regulation.

Separating out the effects of environmental regulation from the myriad of other phenomena affecting consumption and production decisions also is an ongoing challenge. In terms of employment impacts, it has long been observed that even a large-scale air regulation is unlikely to have a noticeable impact on aggregate net U.S. employment. Instead, labor in affected sectors would primarily be reallocated from one productive use to another, and national employment effects from regulation would be small and transitory (e.g., as workers move from one job to another) (Arrow et al., 1996). Given the literature to date, this is also likely to be true when evaluating the effects of environmental regulation on productivity or plant entry and exit decisions.

If the economy is operating at less than full employment, economic theory does not clearly indicate either magnitude or direction of the total impact (Schmalansee & Stavins, 2011). For example, an early government-sponsored macroeconomic study (U.S. CEQ et al., 1972) estimated that pollution abatement spending was stimulative of employment in the United States at a time of less than full employment. Likewise, the Congressional Budget Office identified U.S. EPA regulations that reduce mercury from power plants and hazardous air pollutants from industrial boilers and process heaters as potentially leading to short-run net increases in economic growth and employment driven by capital investments to comply with the regulations (CBO, 2011). An important fundamental research question is how to accommodate slackness in the economy—when labor and other resources are not fully and efficiently employed—as a structural feature in economic models. This feature may be important in evaluating the impact of large-scale environmental regulation on employment (Smith, 2012, 2015). 25

Incorporating Benefits into Welfare and Economic Impact Analyses

To describe the complete incidence of a regulation, one should consider not only the distribution of costs but also benefits. However, folding benefits into the evaluation of economic impacts is complicated. An analyst would need to understand to what extent certain types of households differentially benefit from reductions in emissions. Another important consideration would be whether workers enjoy health improvements that enhance their productivity, thus reducing the long-term impact of the regulation on producers and labor. In practice, the evaluation of how costs and benefits are distributed across economic sectors is usually evaluated separately.

Note that, absent a credible way to represent environmental externalities in a general equilibrium model—or the benefits that accrue to society from mitigating them—an assessment of the welfare and economic impacts derived from this approach is incomplete. The research studying the importance of incorporating the environment in analyses of the economic effects of environmental policies is still developing, though the results have thus far been robust in the conclusion that estimates of the overall economic impacts of a policy will be significantly biased if only the costs of compliance are included.

Although the beneficial impacts of environmental policies need to be incorporated in an assessment of their economy-wide effects to achieve unbiased results, there are numerous technical challenges to developing robust linkages between the economy and the environment. For example, to date the primary approach to including mortality risk reductions in CGE models has been to increase the time endowment on the basis of the expected change in the population. on the basis of the typical assumption of homothetic preferences in these models and the relatively small size of such shocks compared with the size of the labor force, this approach values the change in the mortality risk reduction at approximately the wage rate. While analytically convenient, this time endowment approach undervalues households’ willingness to pay for mortality risk reductions by an order of magnitude (Smith, 2012). The discrepancy in how households’ preferences regarding mortality risk are captured raises questions about how this difference affects forecasts of behavioral changes in response to changes in mortality risk. This is an area of future research that will be important for improving our understanding of how human health impacts of environmental policies feed back into the economy.

In addition, as noted by Antoine et al. (2008) and Carbon and Smith (2013), there are a number of data challenges with linking the environment and the economy in applied general equilibrium models. The CGE model requires benchmark estimates of the value for each of the inputs to activities, including the nonmarket inputs supplied by the environment. However, these inputs are often not observed, or at least not recorded, in national economic account statistics. Even in the United States, national or regional data for the time spent engaged in these activities are not complete. Also, the literature has yet to provide readily available estimates for elasticities that relate the ability of households to substitute between land and other market goods when providing activities involving the environment, such as recreation services, and their ability to substitute between these and other activities in their utility function. The fine spatial resolution at which policies impact the environment also presents unique data and methodological challenges, as applied general equilibrium models are often resolved at a fairly aggregate level.

Understanding Labor Productivity Effects

Environmental regulation may also affect labor supply and productivity or employees’ ability to work. While the theoretical framework for analyzing labor supply and productivity effects is analogous to that for labor demand (decomposing a wage change from a consumer’s perspective into income and substitution effects), it is more difficult to study empirically. Although this literature faces empirical challenges, particularly in terms of requiring detailed individual-level labor data for the separation of impacts of reduced exposure to pollution from other factors influencing labor productivity, early work supported by the U.S. EPA found that air quality improvements led to reductions in lost work days (e.g., Ostro, 1987) and increased labor productivity for outdoor workers (Crocker & Horst, 1981). More recently, there has been some limited evidence that worker productivity may improve with better ambient air quality and worsen on days with higher pollution (Graff Zivin & Neidell, 2012; Chang, Graff Zivin, Gross, & Neidell, 2016).

Valuing Employment Impacts in Benefit–Cost Analysis

The standard approach in regulatory analysis has been to analyze employment as an economic impact. However, the great recession in the 2000s spurred new interest in considering the question of whether employment impacts also should be considered as a social cost of regulation (Ferris & McGartland, 2013). Rogerson (2015) notes that an economy-wide model that explicitly accounts for the labor market already incorporates employment effects into its welfare calculation through changes in how the household values consumption and leisure in the utility function. For instance, in the case where a policy lowers employment, it also likely lowers output and consumption but increases leisure. The only way to weigh the cost of lower consumption against the benefit of higher leisure is through a utility function that explicitly values both. Rogerson goes on to observe that this need not apply only to a model with full employment and no price rigidities.

With less than full employment due to a preexisting wage rigidity, the model will reflect that leisure is valued less than employment by households. When Rogerson (2015) examined whether welfare calculations in a highly stylized model are affected by assumptions about how quickly the labor market responds to a policy shock, he found that the size of the labor response has little effect. This is because of the offsetting effects on leisure.

Even at full employment affected sectors may experience transitory effects as workers change jobs (Arrow et al., 1996; Smith, 2015; Kuminoff, Schoellman, & Timmins, 2015). For example, some workers may need to retrain or relocate in anticipation of the new requirements or require time to search for new jobs, while shortages in some sectors or regions could bid up wages to attract workers. It is important to recognize that these adjustments can entail local labor disruptions, and although the aggregate impact on the national workforce is expected to be small, localized changes in employment can still have negative impacts on some individuals and communities and positive impacts on others. If these types of adjustment costs are substantial, excluding them may underestimate the social cost of regulation. 26

Empirical Evidence of the Porter Hypothesis

Mainly on the basis of case studies, Porter (1991) and Porter and van der Linde (1995) argued that well-designed environmental regulations could “trigger innovation that may partially or more than fully offset the costs of complying with them.” While agreeing with some of Porter and van der Linde’s (1995) arguments, such as the desirability of market-based regulation, Palmer, Oates, and Portney (1995) criticized the “Porter hypothesis” as not being broadly generalizable and argued that most regulations have costs to society and should be subject to a benefit–cost test.

Jaffe and Palmer (1997) distinguished “narrow,” “weak,” and “strong” versions of the Porter hypothesis. The narrow version is simply the argument frequently made by economists that flexible regulatory policies give firms greater incentives to innovate and thus are better than prescriptive regulations. The weak version is the argument that properly designed environmental regulations may stimulate innovations that may not have existed otherwise. In the strong version, it is argued that well-designed regulations can spur firms to innovate to such an extent that they can both comply with the regulation and increase profits, which creates a win-win situation. Ambec, Cohen, Elgie, and Lanoie (2013) reviewed empirical evidence for and against the validity of the Porter hypothesis. For the weak version, they concluded that on balance evidence exists that “There is a positive link between environmental regulation and innovation, although the strength of the link varies.” For the strong version of the Porter hypothesis, they found that the majority of studies were not supportive.

In spite of their conclusions, Ambec et al. (2013) noted that “We continue to find conflicting evidence concerning the Porter Hypothesis, alternative theories that might explain it, and oftentimes a misunderstanding of what the Porter Hypothesis does and does not say.” They point to the need for additional research that relies on longitudinal data, the value of improved data and methodologies that better pinpoint the mechanisms by which regulation can lead to innovation, which in turn may increase or decrease costs, and the need for a better understanding of the role of non-regulatory approaches such as reporting or voluntary programs in spurring innovation in abatement technologies.